

Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Prepare for your exams
Study with the several resources on Docsity
Earn points to download
Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan
Community
Ask the community for help and clear up your study doubts
Discover the best universities in your country according to Docsity users
Free resources
Download our free guides on studying techniques, anxiety management strategies, and thesis advice from Docsity tutors
---------------------------------
Typology: Schemes and Mind Maps
1 / 2
This page cannot be seen from the preview
Don't miss anything!
Notes on Chapter 8. Two Worlds in Capital in the Twenty-First Century by Piketty & Goldhammer. (2014). Harvard University Press. The chapter 8, ‘Two Worlds’, is located within the third part of the book, which is entitled ‘The structure of Inequality’. In this chapter, Piketty presents his study on the historical evolution of inequality in the world, seeking to answer a specific question: how and why has the structure of inequality changed since the nineteenth century? The measure of inequality Piketty’s study of inequality is based on the use of a particular measurement method, which consists of observing the fluctuations and evolutions of shares of top decile and centile in both national income and wages. In other words, the author argues that most trends of compression and expansion of inequalities are strictly linked to the portion of a country's wealth belonging to the richest 10% and the richest 1% of that same country. Indeed, the author stresses the importance of the top decile (and the top centile) in the structuring of the economic and political landscape. He specifies that he does so by examining inequality of primary incomes - before taxation or transfers - primarily extracting information from income statements (starting in France from 1914 and in the US from 1913) and data on estate taxes. The units of analysis Piketty applies this method of measurement to two cases: the case of France and the case of the United States. This choice of these examples relies on the fact that they are both particularly well- documented – thanks to readily available historical sources - and they display quite simple and straightforward information. Moreover, France is considered very representative of changes observed in several other developed countries, namely European continental countries.
Observing the oscillation of the share of top decile in total income, distinguishing between income from capital and income from labor, allows Piketty to determine direct relations between social and political events and the evolution of “The Limits of Income Tax Returns” I must stress the limits of the fiscal sources used in this chapter: the figures are based solely on income from capital reported in tax returns. In fact, income tax returns are becoming increasingly less accurate sources for studying capital income (due to tax evasion, specially effective to hide investment income, and to the existence of tax exemptions) and it is indispensable to make use of other, complementary sources as well, either microeconomic or macroeconomic. Furthermore, tax returns contain no information about the origin of the capital whose income is being reported.” an identical level of inequality with respect to income from capital can in fact reflect very different situations, and we would never learn anything about these differences if we restricted ourselves to tax return data.” For example, we cannot state that inheritance plays a major role. One consequence is that our series underestimate—probably slightly—the increase of inequality that can be observed in most countries after 1970, and in particular the role of income from capital.