Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting: Fair & Effective for Paris Goals, Study notes of Accounting

The advantages of using consumption-based carbon accounting (CBA) as a target base for achieving the Paris Agreement's emissions reduction goals. CBA can transform the burden-sharing problem into a self-enforcing situation of international coordination among major emitters, increasing overall effectiveness and fairness. The document also explores the implications of CBA for carbon markets and the political feasibility of its adoption.

Typology: Study notes

2021/2022

Uploaded on 09/27/2022

manager33
manager33 🇬🇧

4.4

(34)

241 documents

1 / 12

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
Achieving the Paris Goals: Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting
Marco Grasso
Università degli Studi di Milano-Bicocca
Published in Geoforum, Volume 79, February 2017, Pages 9396
Abstract
To achieve the Paris Agreement abatement goals, the use of consumption-based
carbon accounting (CBA) as a target base, i.e., as a reference scale for emissions
reductions, has potential advantages of fairness, effectiveness, and cost. At the
same time, CBA also has rather high political feasibility. However, CBA has not yet
been adopted, not even experimentally. Nevertheless, major concurrent reasons
suggest that the time is ripe for employing this accounting system as a target base.
Accordingly, this review article indicates a strategy that leverages the potential of
CBA to take advantage of the ripeness of the time through the activation of
governance measures that increase the likelihood of its adoption as a target base.
This strategy can shape converging preferences in support of CBA among
stakeholders belonging to different political traditions and subject to different political
constraints, and increase the chances of this accounting system being adopted as a
target base.
Keywords
Consumption-based carbon accounting, governance systems; international
coordination
Highlights
Consumption-based carbon accounting (CBA) has advantages of fairness,
effectiveness, and cost.
The use of CBA also has rather high political feasibility.
Major concurrent reasons suggest that the time is ripe for employing CBA.
A strategy for promoting the adoption of CBA should shape converging
preferences in its support.
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa

Partial preview of the text

Download Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting: Fair & Effective for Paris Goals and more Study notes Accounting in PDF only on Docsity!

Achieving the Paris Goals: Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting Marco Grasso Università degli Studi di Milano-Bicocca Published in Geoforum, Volume 79, February 2017, Pages 93– 96 Abstract To achieve the Paris Agreement abatement goals, the use of consumption-based carbon accounting (CBA) as a target base, i.e., as a reference scale for emissions reductions, has potential advantages of fairness, effectiveness, and cost. At the same time, CBA also has rather high political feasibility. However, CBA has not yet been adopted, not even experimentally. Nevertheless, major concurrent reasons suggest that the time is ripe for employing this accounting system as a target base. Accordingly, this review article indicates a strategy that leverages the potential of CBA to take advantage of the ripeness of the time through the activation of governance measures that increase the likelihood of its adoption as a target base. This strategy can shape converging preferences in support of CBA among stakeholders belonging to different political traditions and subject to different political constraints, and increase the chances of this accounting system being adopted as a target base. Keywords Consumption-based carbon accounting, governance systems; international coordination Highlights

  • Consumption-based carbon accounting (CBA) has advantages of fairness, effectiveness, and cost.
  • The use of CBA also has rather high political feasibility.
  • Major concurrent reasons suggest that the time is ripe for employing CBA.
  • A strategy for promoting the adoption of CBA should shape converging preferences in its support.

1. Introduction Although the Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) part of the 2015 Paris Agreement testify to an unprecedented global breadth of climate initiatives, they do not set emissions cuts sufficient to achieve the goal of safely limiting the global temperatures increase (Rogelj et al., 2016; Young, 2016). In fact, to attain the targets set by article 2(1),^1 major emitters must commit in the near future to cutbacks larger than the pledges they have made to meet the Paris goals. This implies a further proportional distribution of the abatements burden; a challenge that, despite the many difficulties that climate change poses, continue to be the toughest and most crucial problem of international climate policy (Keohane and Victor, 2011). Fortunately, the Paris Agreement envisions a periodic review, known as the ‘global stocktake’, of progress towards achievement of its goals. The first global stocktake should be undertaken in 2023, and thereafter every five years unless differently decided. This is an unparalleled occasion to change some ‘rules of the game’ that have so far hampered adequate emissions cuts: first and foremost those related to carbon accounting, whose role ‘is crucial for informed decision-making on how to curb the rise [of emissions]’ (Nature Climate Change 2016, p. 975), and for the eventual achievement of the Paris goals (Tollefson, 2016). In particular, with respect to addressing the additional carbon abatements required to strengthen the otherwise inadequate Paris Agreement, this review article investigates the advantages of using consumption-base carbon accounting (CBA) as a target base, i.e., as a reference scale for internationally agreed emissions reductions (Steininger et al., 2016), and puts forward a possible strategy for adopting it. 2. The Potential of Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting CBA measures emissions associated with the final consumption of goods and services and is calculated by adding to production-based accounting (PBA), which is currently the only accounting system used under the UNFCCC, emissions generated to produce imported goods and services and subtracting those associated with exported goods and services. CBA is not an overall panacea (see Liu, 2015), but, in a context of increasing sensitivity to governing global consumption patterns (Dauvergne, 2010), it makes it possible to focus on high-consumption lifestyles (^1) Article 2(1) of the Paris Agreement requires at paragraph (a) that the increase in the global average temperature will be kept ‘to well below 2 °C above pre-industrial levels’ and that efforts ‘to limit the temperature increase to 1.5 °C above pre-industrial levels’ will be pursued.

responsibility for past emissions is higher and whose capacity to solve the problem is greater, however both are measured. With regard to effectiveness, it should first be pointed out that countries’ motivations to participate in collaborative abatement actions are mostly driven by its place in the international system. More specifically by its relative material power capabilities, shaped by indirect and complex domestic-level systemic pressures, often morally relevant (Rose, 1998; Purdon, 2014; Oberthür, 2016; Vogler, 2016). Countries’ motivations in international climate politics can in fact be usefully framed in terms of, and grounded in, agreed normative beliefs on responsibility for past emissions and the role of relative gains; issues whose sensitivity has greatly increased in the recent past (Grasso and Roberts, 2014). International emissions abatements, in fact, redefine moral concerns and relative gains dynamics for the largest emitters, and especially so for the most powerful ones, China and the U.S. (Grundig, 2006; Oberthür, 2016). Grasso and Roberts (2014), for instance, shows that the relative gains dynamics of a CBA-based distribution of abatements confirm that costs should be acceptable to China, which would have substantial headroom and ultimately less stringent abatement targets. At the same time, CBA would not excessively penalize the U.S., since its relative gains would diminish to an extent negligible compared with overall spending to address the climate crisis. Such outcomes seem ultimately to prove that China and the U.S. – countries with traditionally conflicting objectives in relation to international emissions reductions – might forgo part of their narrow short-term interests in order to stabilize the climate system. The involvement of additional countries in mitigation action would be fostered also by the minor variations of relative gains among the other major emitters

  • apart from the EU, whose reasons for further engagement in international emissions reductions are mainly grounded in its intent to regain primacy in climate policy within a coalition-building strategy (Bäckstrand and Elgström, 2013; Oberthür, 2016). Accordingly, the rationale for the greater effectiveness in terms of agreed international abatements resulting from the use of CBA as a target base lies in the fact that the different spaces of emissions accounting modify the theoretical conceptualization and empirical configuration of a critical, morally connoted domestic systemic pressure: responsibility for past emissions. When this novel conceptualization of responsibility determined by CBA is applied to distributing the

emissions cuts among countries, it produces a shift in the allocation of the related burdens that indicates a more feasible allocation of abatements costs. In fact, the resulting dynamics of material power capabilities as measured by relative gains are more acceptable to, and therefore facilitate further collaboration among (Keohane and Nye, 1989), the major emitters (Purdon, 2014). Furthermore, the structural power exercised by these more powerful countries, especially if China and the U.S. took the lead, can induce other countries to participate in wider and more compelling action on emissions reductions. CBA sheds also light on the appropriateness of carbon markets and of their accounting practices in relation to the spaces where processes, activities and mechanisms that remove greenhouse gases from the atmosphere take place. In particular, the adoption of CBA as a target base can disprove the inability, feared by part of the relevant literature (e.g., Knox-Hynes, 2013), of carbon accounting practices to adapt to the complexity of carbon emissions. Rather, the re-distribution of countries’ burdens produced by CBA, as opposed to the one determined by the current PBA, confirms the view that carbon markets are necessarily the result of shifting and negotiable boundaries, given that they are the techno-political product of expert knowledge and political practices (Kama, 2014). The strengths of CBA are complemented by its rather high political feasibility. In normative terms, given its capacity to shift the emissions burden to those who shoulder it less than justice demands, it would satisfy the core moral principle for a more just social arrangement in this context (Grasso, 2016). This feature, combined with the stability of CBA (i.e., its maintainability once it has been implemented) and accessibility (i.e., the existence of a practical route for its implementation), fulfil the requirements for determining its normative political feasibility (Gilabert and Lawford- Smith, 2012; Grasso, 2016). CBA thus would not only advance international action to abate emissions effectively, it would also favour carbon-exporting countries, so that its political feasibility should be quite high in those regions (Ashton, 2012). At the same time, the positive political feasibility of CBA crucially depends on countries’ institutional capacity (Burnell, 2012).

3. The Right Timing for Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting Despite its potential and the rich and almost consistently favourable literature, CBA has not yet been adopted, not even experimentally. Nevertheless, major concurrent

international climate politics. This circumstance improves their willingness to combat climate change and eventually to develop, also with the support of richer countries, the necessary technical and political capacities, including those for adopting CBA.

4. A Strategy for Introducing Consumption-Based Carbon Accounting The potential of CBA coupled with the favourability of the timing make it possible to delineate a strategy for its implementation as a reference scale for emissions reductions. This strategy is articulated into concurrent spheres that can be understood as an attempt to leverage the strengths of CBA to take advantage of the ripeness of the time through the activation of governance approaches, structures, instruments, and actions that shape preferences in order to increase the likelihood of a swifter and smoother implementation of CBA as a target base. The adoption of CBA should first be carried out by a limited group of major emitters, belonging both to the developed and developing world. With their leadership and structural power, other countries will more willingly follow suit. This would avoid the cumbersome nature of the UNFCCC decision processes, and the resulting enhanced viability would respond to the urgency of the climate crisis by making the achievement of ambitious abatement goals possible. To extend the adoption of CBA to the remaining countries at a later stage, the entire process could be formalized under the UNFCCC. The limitation of initial action to a restricted group of first movers would also dramatically reduce the transaction costs of implementing CBA. In the midst the current pervasive economic slowdown, the lower the transaction costs, the more politically and individually acceptable CBA implementation becomes. Given the centrality of justice in its various understandings in the climate debate, the greater distributive justice of CBA should be supplemented by procedural elements of justice. At the same time, the governance systems to implement CBA should be legitimate, i.e., they should have the moral right to apply this accounting system and be believed to have such a right (Buchanan and Keohane, 2006). Fully-fledged notions of justice and legitimacy that take account of intergenerational considerations further increase the already high political feasibility of CBA, since they improve the support among agents involved with different substantive commitments and provide a useful ground for objectively resolving the deadlock on emissions abatements. This comprehensive ethical dimension would also comply with the necessity to broaden the scope of climate ethics to accommodate the challenges raised by carbon markets

and the involved processes of carbon commodification (Randall, 2011). In particular, this inclusive perspective can help forestall the tendency of carbon markets to nature’s neo-liberalisation (e.g., Higgins et al., 2015), by returning to individuals’ values and judgment and thus avoiding the mere logic of capital accumulation. Similarly, to increase the acceptability of addressing emissions at the consumption stage, actions that focus the attention on the role of consumption as the ultimate source of carbon emissions are needed to favour the smooth adoption of CBA as a target base. In particular, it would be necessary to introduce a wide range of local and international initiatives that question the practical and moral implications of a global socio-economic system offshoring a disproportionate amount of the costs of producing goods and services largely consumed in the rich countries to the world’s poorer and more socially and environmentally vulnerable regions. These initiatives should, in fact, increase the willingness to consider also consumption, besides production, as a major culprit for carbon emissions, and therefore an additional locus where they should be accounted for. The greater institutional capacity of the major emerging economies makes them ready to take advantage of other forms of collaboration on climate issues that can at the same time usefully spur the adoption of CBA. In particular, more affluent large emitters should extend a green ladder to emerging and developing economies through technology transfer, sufficient and predictable financial assistance, technical and institutional support, and capacity building. Moreover, richer large emitters would have a further specific obligation to provide the necessary technological constituents of the carbon economy for adopting CBA: in particular tools, methodologies, training, knowledge for collecting and calculating consumption-based figures. These forms of collaboration would augment the fairness and feasibility of adopting CBA in the beneficiary regions. In sum, to favour the introduction of CBA it is important to weaken the resistances against this accounting system through appropriate governance responses able to stimulate and aggregate the support of all stakeholders involved. This would be much more effective in promoting a timely adoption of CBA as a target base than any form of imposition or trust in the mere vision of politicians. In fact, in the current fragmented and multipolar international climate order, countries’ preferences largely differ, authority is divided, and compliance with any initiative depends solely on voluntary agreements. Therefore, feasible international climate action needs to

References Ashton, J. (2012). Oral Evidence given to the UK Energy and Climate Change Committee, 21 June 2012; http://www.publications.parliament.uk/pa/cm201213/cmselect/cmenergy/392/120621. htm. Bäckstrand, K. and Elgström, O. (2013). The EU's role in climate change negotiations: from leader to “leadiator”. Journal of European Public Policy , 20, 1369-

Bows, A. and Barrett, J. (2010). Cumulative emission scenarios using a consumption-based approach: A glimmer of hope. Carbon Manag ement, 1 , 161-175. Buchanan, A. E. and Keohane, R. O. (2006). The legitimacy of global governance institutions. Ethics & International Affairs , 20, 405-437. Burnell, P. (2012). Democracy, democratization and climate change: Complex relationships. Democratization , 19, 813-842. Dauvergne, P. (2010). The problem of consumption. Global Environmental Politics , 10(2), 1-10. European Uninon (EU) (2011). /* COM/2011/0112final*/ Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, the Council, the European Economic and Social Committee and the Committee of the Regions, A Roadmap for moving to a competitive low carbon economy in 2050; http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal- content/EN/TXT/HTML/?uri=CELEX:52011DC0112&from=EN Gilabert, P. and Lawford-Smith, H. ( 2012 ). Political feasibility: A conceptual exploration. Political Studies 60, 809 - 825. Grasso, M. (2016). The political feasibility of consumption-based carbon accounting. New Political Economy , 21, 401-413. Grasso, M. and Roberts, J. T. (2014). A compromise to break the climate impasse. Nature Climate Change , 4, 543- 549 Grundig, F. (2006). Patterns of international cooperation and the explanatory power of relative gains: An analysis of cooperation on global climate change, ozone depletion, and international trade. International Studies Quarterly , 50, 781-801. Harris, P. G. and Symons, J. (2013). Norm conflict in climate governance: Greenhouse gas accounting and the problem of consumption. Global Environmental Politics , 13(1), 9-29.

Higgins, V., Dibden, J. and Cocklin, C. (2015). Private agri-food governance and greenhouse gas abatement: Constructing a corporate carbon economy. Geoforum , 66, 75-84. Oberthür, S. (2016). The European Union in crisis: What future for the EU in international climate policy? IES (Institute for European Studies) Policy Brief 2016/18. Jamieson, D. (2013). Consequentialism, climate change, and the road ahead. Chicago Journal of International Law , 13, 439-468. Kama, K. (2014). On the borders of the market: EU emissions trading, energy security, and the technopolitics of ‘carbon leakage’. Geoforum , 51, 202-212. Keohane, R.O. and Nye, J.S. (1989). Power and Interdependence. Boston: Little- Brown. Keohane, R. O. and Victor, D. G. (2011). The regime complex for climate change. Perspectives on Politics , 9, 7-23. Keohane, R. O. and Victor, D. G. (2016). Cooperation and discord in global climate policy. Nature Climate Change , 6, 570-575. Knox-Hayes, J. (2013). The spatial and temporal dynamics of value in financialization: Analysis of the infrastructure of carbon markets. Geoforum , 50, 117-

Liu, L. (2015). A critical examination of the consumption-based accounting approach: Has the blaming of consumers gone too far?. WIREs Climate Change , 6, 1-8. Nature Climate Change (2014). Editorial: Window of opportunity. Nature Climate Change, 4, 1037. Nature Climate Change (2016). Editorial: Carbon accounting. Nature Climate Change, 6, 935. Oberthür, S. (2016). Reflections on global climate politics post Paris: Power, interests and polycentricity. The International Spectator , doi: 10.1080/03932729.2016.1242256. Osborne, T. (2015). Tradeoffs in carbon commodification: A political ecology of common property forest governance. Geoforum , 67, 64-77. Peters, G. P., Davis, G. P. and Andrew, R. (2012). A synthesis of carbon in international trade. Biogeosciences , 9, 3247-3276.