Docsity
Docsity

Prepare for your exams
Prepare for your exams

Study with the several resources on Docsity


Earn points to download
Earn points to download

Earn points by helping other students or get them with a premium plan


Guidelines and tips
Guidelines and tips

a Writing a research report is an essential aspect of any research project as it serves a, Lecture notes of Finance

1. Analyzing the global market: Understanding the global market and the potential opportunities and risks associated with it is essential for making informed international business decisions. 2. Assessing the competitive landscape: Knowing the competitive landscape in the global market is important for making informed decisions. 3. Understanding the legal and regulatory environment: It is important to understand the legal and regulatory environment in the countries where the business is operating. 4. Developing a global strategy: Developing a global strategy that takes into account the different markets, cultures, and regulations is essential for success. 5. Establishing a presence in the global market: Establishing a presence in the global market is important for success. This includes setting up offices, hiring local staff, and developing relationships with local partners. 6. Developing a global brand: Developing a global brand is important for success in the global market. This

Typology: Lecture notes

2022/2023

Uploaded on 06/23/2023

shreya-butola-1
shreya-butola-1 🇮🇳

1 document

1 / 29

Toggle sidebar

This page cannot be seen from the preview

Don't miss anything!

bg1
Unit Highlights:
The mercantilist Thesis on Trade.
The Theory of Absolute Advantage.
The Theory of Comparative Advantage.
Gains from International Trade.
The Heckscher-Ohlin model.
The Rybezynski Theorem.
Theories of International Trade
pf3
pf4
pf5
pf8
pf9
pfa
pfd
pfe
pff
pf12
pf13
pf14
pf15
pf16
pf17
pf18
pf19
pf1a
pf1b
pf1c
pf1d

Partial preview of the text

Download a Writing a research report is an essential aspect of any research project as it serves a and more Lecture notes Finance in PDF only on Docsity!

Unit Highlights:

 The mercantilist Thesis on Trade.

 The Theory of Absolute Advantage.

 The Theory of Comparative Advantage.

 Gains from International Trade.

 The Heckscher-Ohlin model.

 The Rybezynski Theorem.

Theories of International Trade

 The Stolper-Samuelson Theorem.

Mercantilists

advocated

protective tariff

to discourage

imports.

Important

questions of

trade concern

gains from

trade, patterns

of trade, and

terms of trade.

keep wages low, protecting agriculture and industry, keeping the trade balance

favourable and so on.

We are primarily concerned with mercantilist views on trade. The mercantilists

encouraged a favourable trade balance because by ensuring larger inflows of silver

and gold than outflows it helped stockpiling of these precious metals. And to keep

the trade balance as favourable as possible, the value of exports should be

maximized and that of imports minimized. They advocated protective tariffs to

discourage the imports of luxury items, and import of essential raw materials only

were viewed with less concern. In short, the mercantilist policies were all designed

and implemented to restrict and regulate international trade which was seen not as

a virtue in itself but rather as an instrument of building up a wealthy and powerful

nation.

Three Pertinent Questions Regarding Trade

The mercantilists missed the issues which really mattered in the case of

international trade. The economists who subsequently raised and tried to answer

these pertinent questions are known as classical economists. Among them were

such notables as Adam Smith, David Ricardo and John Stuart Mill. They raised

the following three sets of questions:

  1. What are the gains from trade, if any? What are the sources of gains from

trade and what factors determine the division of these gains among the trading

partners? Or, to put it negatively, what is the cost of preventing free trade and

of trying to attain self-sufficiency?

  1. Should trade prove to be mutually beneficial, what determines the patterns of

trade? In other words, which goods should each trading country export and

import in order to reap the benefits of trade? And related to this is the

question: What factors determine the international allocation of factor of

production?

  1. What factors determine the terms of trade (i.e. the prices at which goods are

sold internationally) at which trade has to take place, if it is to be beneficial to

at least one country and harmful to none? Do such price ratios necessarily

exit?

Needless to say, these questions form the bedrock of the pure theory of

international trade.

Absolute and Comparative Advantage

The mercantilist ideas about regulating foreign trade by encouraging exports and

discouraging imports drew sharp reactions later from economists and political

philosophers. Noted among them were John Locke and David Hume. But the most

convincing rebuttal came from Adam Smith who epitomized the spirit of

individualism, dominant in the mid-eighteenth century. He brilliantly exposed the

fallacies of the mercantilist doctrine of regulated trade and demonstrated that free

international trade based on international division of labour could benefit all

trading partners.

The Theory of Absolute Advantage

Any theory of international trade must cope with answering two basic questions:

(a) what determines the patterns of trade, and (b) who gains from trade. Adam

Smith's answer draws on the idea of benefits from voluntary exchange following

Free trades

argued that

often two

countries could

make

themselves

better off by

trading than in

isolation.

In this theory,

costs refer to

labour cost of

production.

specialization based on the division of labour. The shoemaker and the tailor can

concentrate on their own lines of production and then exchange each other's goods.

This system of specialization and exchange could make both better off than when

each made both shoes and shirts. Adam Smith extended this principle of division

of labour to nations engaged in international exchange of goods and services. He

argued that under certain circumstances, to be elaborated below, two countries

could make themselves better off by trading than in isolation. His explanation

known as the theory of absolute advantage, though incomplete, is a brilliant

exposition of the virtues of free trade.

It should be understood that the advantages referred to by Adam Smith are based

on differences in the cost of production. Under the labour theory of value to which

classical economists, including Adam Smith, subscribed, the cost differences

translate into price differences in a straightforward fashion. Absolute cost

differences then must lead to absolute price differences which form the basis of

mutually profitable trade. Costs refer to labour costs of production. This implies

that other factors of production such as land and capital are used in some fixed

proportion to labour so that their identities could be merged with that of labour (as

a single input). Besides, the technology of production is such that for each unit of

output of any given good the amount of labour required is fixed irrespective of the

level of output. For example, if the unit cost of production of cloth is 5 labour

hours when the output of cloth is 10 units, then the unit cost would still be 5

labour-hours when the output is 100, 10,000 or 100,000 units. The constant unit

cost assumption applies to goods in the home country as well as the foreign

country, but the unit costs can vary across goods and between countries.

Let us now examine how the ratio of unit costs determines the ratio of goods

prices within a given country in the absence of trade. Hypothetical data on the

costs of production of two goods - cloth and food- in two countries, Thailand and

Japan are presented in Table 2.1 below :

Table 2.

Labour Costs of Production (Hours)

Country 1 unit of food 1 unit of cloth

Thailand 15 30

Japan 30 15

It is clear from Table 2.1 that to produce a unit of cloth Thailand requires twice as

much labour as to produce a unit of food. Therefore, in isolation (a situation

usually known as autarky) one unit of cloth will exchange for two units of food.

By analogous reasoning, the autarky price of a unit of food in Japan will be two

units of cloth.

Table: 2.

Country Price per Unit

Food Cloth

Thailand 1

unit of cloth

2 units of food

Japan 2 units of cloth 1

unit of food.

A trade on the

basis of

comparative

advantage is

profitable.

A country is

said to have

comparative

advantage in

production of

the good in

which its

opportunity

cost of

production is

lower.

1874). Interestingly, it remains one of the oldest and still serviceable theories in

economics.

What is then, comparative advantage? Let us recall that if a country can produce

all goods at lower unit (labour) costs than the other, the former is said to possess

absolute advantage in all goods. In this sense, the costs figures given in Table 2.

indicate, that Thailand has absolute advantage in the production of both food and

cloth. The point here is whether there can be a profitable trade in terms of

comparative advantage, a concept best understood if expressed in terms of

opportunity costs.

Table 2.3 : Labour Costs of Production (Hours)

Country 1 unit of food (a

LF

) 1 unit of cloth (a

LC

Thailand

Japan

Table 2.4 : Opportunity Costs of Production

Country 1 unit of food (a

LF

/ a

LC

) 1 unit of cloth (a

LC

/ a

LF

Thailand

Japan

The opportunity cost of food in terms of cloth is the amount of cloth given up in

order to release resources for producing an additional unit of food. The

opportunity costs of one good in terms of the other based on labour cost figures of

Table 2.3 are shown in Table 2.4. For example, to produce a unit of food in

Thailand will require 15 labour hours which, if released from the production of

cloth, will entail a sacrifice of

5

6

unit of cloth. Table 2.4 also shows that the

opportunity cost of food (in terms of cloth) is lower in Thailand than in Japan. On

the other hand, the opportunity cost of producing cloth is lower in Japan. And this

is so despite the fact that unit (labour) cost of producing food and cloth are both

lower in Thailand.

A country is said to have comparative advantage in production of the good in

which its opportunity cost of production is lower. Therefore, on the basis of Table

2.4, we can say that Thailand has comparative advantage in food and Japan in

cloth (although Japan has absolute advantage in both).

The theory of comparative advantage then asserts that a country will gain by

exporting the good in which it has comparative advantage, while importing the

good in which it has comparative disadvantage (higher opportunity costs). Note

that for the notion of comparative advantage to be meaningful there must be at

least two countries and at least two goods.

Gains from Trade in the Ricardian Model of Comparative Advantage

It can be easily shown that both the trading countries (here Thailand and Japan)

are better off by trade following the lines of specialization indicated by

comparative advantage. If Japan can import one unit of food from Thailand at a

Both the trading

countries are

shown to be

better off by

trade on the

basis of

comparative

advantage.

The total output

of food depends

on the amount

of cloth,

because supply

of labour and

a LC

/a LF

are

constant.

price lower than 1.33 units of cloth, it clearly stands to gain. On the other hand,

Thailand gains if it can import a unit of cloth at a price lower than 1.2 units of

food (Table 2.4). Let us suppose that the international price settles at 1 unit of

cloth for 1 unit of food (which is in the range indicated above). Then Japan gains

because through trade it gets 1 unit of food by sacrificing 1 unit of cloth, while

under autarky it has to give up 1.33 units of cloth to produce and consume one

unit of cloth. The additional 0.33 unit of cloth (saved) can be consumed or can be

exported to import more food or the country may even choose to consume the

same levels of food and cloth as under autarky, while the workers enjoy more

leisure. By similar reasoning, it can also be shown that at the given international

terms of exchange, Thailand too is better off through trade (exporting food and

importing cloth) than in autarky. It gets 1 unit of cloth for 1 unit of food by trade

and thus saves 0.2 unit of food which it can dispose of in three ways (or any

combination): consuming more food at home, exporting to Japan for more cloth, or

allowing the worker more leisure made possible by consuming the autarkic levels

of consumption of food and cloth.

Ricardian Comparative Advantage & the Extent of Specialization

As we have seen, Ricardo assumed constant average and marginal costs of

production irrespective of the levels of output (by assuming constant labour

productivities for all scales of output). We now want to explore what implication

does this assumption have for the extent of specialization in each country, and in

the process we will examine Ricardian conclusions diagrammatically. Let a LF

and a LC

be the amount of labour needed to produce a unit of food and a unit of

cloth respectively. With a fixed supply of labour, L, and these input co-efficients,

the total output of food (Q F

) and of cloth (Q C

) are technologically related in the

following way :

a

LF

Q
F
  • a

LC

Q
C
= L

or, Q

F

L

a

LF

a

LC

a

LF

. Q
C

Clearly Q F

depends linearly on the amount of Q C

produced, because a LC

/a LF

is

a constant (by assumption). The relation is diagrammatically expressed in Fig 2.

by the linear production possibilities curve, AB. The slope of the line indicates

constant opportunity cost of one good in terms of the other (considering labour

costs only). For example , if a LC

=18 and a LF

=15, then to produce every

additional unit of cloth the country must sacrifice 1.2 (=18÷15) units of food. In

the absence of trade, therefore, one unit of cloth will exchange for 1.2 units of

food in Thailand (see Table 2.4).

Note that with the constant production possibilities curve like AB, the internal

(pre-trade) price ratio is solely determined by the slope of the production

possibilities curve (i.e by the relative labour productivities in the two goods). The

demand (the taste pattern) had no role to play in the relative price determination as

long both the goods are consumed. Apparently this sounds odd. In Fig. 2.1 two

indifference curves (representing two different taste patterns) are tangent to AB at

points R and R'. Clearly, if the taste patterns change, the country may shift the

consumption (and production) point from R to R', and the price ratio remains the

Free trade

makes both

countries better

off, by

expanding the

consumption

opportunity sets

of both.

to reflect the fact that cloth is cheaper in Japan, while food is cheaper in Thailand

(because

OB
OA
OB*
OA*

As stated before. there exists an opportunity for mutually beneficial trade, if

Thailand exports food and Japan exports cloth. But at what price? Clearly the

price of cloth should be somewhere between absolute values of slopes of the two

linear production possibilities curves (AB and AB), i.e. between

OA

OB

and

OA*

OB*

. The Ricardian model does not offer any mechanism for unique price

determination. But whatever price is established in equilibrium, it must exhibit two

features : (i) the relative equilibrium price of cloth (and so also the equilibrium

price of food) must be the same in the two countries, and (ii) it should be such that

the value of exports of each country at the price must be matched by the value of

imports from the other.

To see diagrammatically that comparative cost difference can lead to mutually

profitable trade, let us go back to Fig. 2.2. In each country, the production and

consumption possibilities before trade are the same (only what is produced can be

consumed). After trade, the consumption possibilities set gets larger, though the

sets of production possibilities remain unaltered. For example if the equilibrium

price ratio is 1:1, then the consumption possibilities set for Thailand is AOC

rather AOB (and AOC is larger than AOB). Similarly the consumption

possibilities set for Japan after trade is given by BOC which is larger than

BOA, representing pre-trade consumption possibilities. Not surprisingly, free

trade can make both countries better off, because of the expansion of the

consumption opportunity sets. But while the technology difference may not lead to

complete specialization in consumption, it may do so in production. Usually

Thailand will completely specialize in the production of food (consuming cloth

from imports only) and Japan in cloth (meeting need for food entirely from

imports), because not doing so amounts to giving up an opportunity for

betterment. As we shall see later, the only exception to the conclusion of complete

specialization and the Ricardian assumptions to the situation is when one of the

two trading countries is much larger than the other.

Questions for Review

MCQ’s (Tick (√) the correct [most appv.] answer)

  1. The Mercantilists

A. rejected all trade and advocated a closed economy

B. encouraged exports and discouraged imports

C. wanted to make the country wealth

D. both B and C

E. None of the above.

  1. Trade will take place between two countries if-

A. comparative costs differ between them

B. price differ between them

C. A and B being true, they fail to settle on the terms of exchange

D. A and B being true, they agree on the terms of exchange

None of the above.

  1. In the Ricardian theory of comparative advantage the relative price of two

goods within a country determined

A. solely by technology

B. solely by taste patterns

C. partly by taste patterns

D. all of the above.

  1. In the Ricardian theory,

A. the average cost (AC) equals marginal cost (MC)

B. AC>MC
C. AC<MC

D. we have usually complete specialization

E. A & D.
  1. In the post-trade equilibrium, the relative equilibrium price will be equal in the

two countries. Therefore,

A. trade will case until price change for one reason or another

B. trade will continue

C. trade will be balanced

D. Both B & C

E. None.

Broad Questions :

  1. Briefly discuss the mercantilist thesis on trade.
  2. Discuss the theory of absolute advantage and point out its limitations.
  3. Country A and country B both produce food and cloth. A has comparative

advantage in cloth. Does it imply that B has comparative advantage in food?

Demonstrate with an example.

Short Questions

  1. The Mercantilists wanted to make the state as powerful (in terms of wealth) as

possible. Why? Was wealth a means to an end, or an end in itself?

  1. What are the three pertinent questions regarding trade? Briefly explain.
  2. “Absolute advantage is a sufficient condition for profitable trade, but it is not

a necessary condition.” Do you agree? why?

  1. “The Ricardian theory seems strange, because it explains price formation

without ever considering the demand conditions.” Do you agree?

  1. Explain why trade enables each country to expand its consumption

opportunity sets.

The relative size

is irrelevant for

explaining trade

patterns, but not

so for terms of

exchange.

Ricardian scheme. The really crucial factor is the difference in technologies. Let

us see why the size and taste differences don't really matter, as long as the

technology (represented by the labour productions) remains the same. As we have

seen, taste differences play no role in price formation, their only role being

determination of relative quantities consumed. The size of the labour force

determines the position of the production possibility curves of the two countries. If

the technology is the same, their slope will be the same, and therefore price

differences will not emerge. We can then say that technology differences lead to

cost difference irrespective of similarity or otherwise of tastes and size of the

countries concerned. But this statement should be carefully interpreted. If one of

the two countries are uniformly superior to the other in technology, relative cost

differences will not appear. To see why, suppose that Thailand can produce a unit

of output of either commodity with 20% fewer labour hours that would be

required in Japan. For simplicity assume that Japan and Thailand have labour

force of the same size. Then the production possibilities curve for Thailand will be

uniformly outward by 20% (compared to that for Japan), but there will be no

difference in their slopes. Therefore, the effect of 20% superiority is like that of

having a 20% larger labour force in Thailand with the same labour productivity in

the two countries. Pre-trade relative price being the same, there is no opportunity

to gain from trade.

Relative Size of Countries and the Extent of Specialization

We have just seen why the relative sizes of the countries (measured in terms of

relative sizes of the labour force) do not influence the patterns of trade. It should

be emphasized however that while the relative size is irrelevant for trade patterns,

it is not so for determining the international terms of exchange, i.e. the terms of

trade. If one country is much larger than the other, the international price may not

lie strictly between the cost ratios in each country. It could be that the equilibrium

terms of trade will be identical to those prevailing in the larger country before

trade, implying that the larger country derives no benefit from free trade (though

the smaller country does). 'Bigness' is then not necessarily a boon; and in fact, the

opposite may be true in the field of international trade.

Fig 2.

When can this happen? Consider two countries, India and Nepal. India has

comparative advantage in the production of tea, while Nepal has this advantage in

timber. India being a very big country compared to Nepal, it cannot hope to meet

all its demand for timber through imports from Nepal (assume that there are only

two countries in the world, India and Nepal). Therefore, India must produce along

with tea perhaps a large quantity of timber too. But then the price of timber must

reflect the costs of production at home which implies that the international price

Ricardian

theory is robust:

it is valid even

when non-

labour costs are

included.

The marginal

rate of

transformation

is opportunity

cost of

cloth in terms of

food.

which will prevail is the pre-trade relative price in India. In Fig. 2.3, the slope of

the line GD reflects the pre-trade and post-trade relative price of tea in India. At

the consumption point (P), India's demand for timber is PQ, of which only PR can

be obtained from Nepal. The rest (RQ) must be produced domestically. Therefore,

India produces at S (rather than at D under complete specialization) and consumes

at P. The result is incomplete specialization in Tea, a consequence of (its) relative

size.

Comparative Advantage under a More General Theory of Production

We have shown that a country enjoys comparative advantage in the Ricardian

sense, if its relative opportunity costs of production is lower than that of the other

country in a certain commodity. The opportunity costs were, however, calculated

on the basis of labour costs alone, because the classical economists believed in the

labour theory of value. Furthermore, the labour costs of production of a unit of

any commodity was constant over the entire range of output. As a result, output of

a commodity could be expanded at a constant opportunity cost.

The dependence of the classical notion of comparative advantage on the labour

theory of value as well as (on) the assumption of constant opportunity costs in a

major drawback. Labour theory of value is too restrictive, while the constant

opportunity cost assumption is empirically questionable. Therefore, it is important

to ask: Does the basic conclusion of the Ricardian theory of comparative

advantage remain valid, even after the notion of Ricardian opportunity cost is

replaced by a more general notion in which non-labour factors of production are

explicitly taken into account and factor substitution is allowed? Fortunately, the

answer is 'yes', because in the 1930s Gottfried Haberler has shown that the

principal prediction of the Ricardian theory about trade patterns stands unaffected

even when production takes place under increasing opportunity costs with many

factors of production cooperating. Despite the changed assumption about the

nature of production processes, it is still true that a country will export the

commodity in which it has a comparative advantage and import the one in which it

has a comparative disadvantage.

Recall that the opportunity cost of cloth (in terms of food) is the amount of food

that must be given up in order to produce an additional unit of cloth (When all

factors of production are fully and efficiently employed in the production of either

or both the goods). When the units of food sacrificed for an additional unit of cloth

go on increasing as the amount of cloth production increases, we have a situation

of increasing opportunity costs. In this case, the production possibilities curve will

be concave to the origin as shown by MN in Fig. 2.4.

The (absolute) slope of MN at any point

shows the rate at which food can be

transformed into cloth in the technological

sense. This rate is called the marginal rate

of transformation (MRT) in production. For

example, the (absolute) slope of MN is

greater at R' than at R, indicating that more

food needs to be sacrificed to increase cloth

production at R' than at R. In other words,

the marginal rate of transformation (which

is nothing but the opportunity cost of cloth

This tendency

of the relative

price of cloth to

change under

the impact of

trade flows will

continue until

the price is the

same in both the

countries and

the trade is

balanced.

In panel (a) of Fig 2.5, the common production and consumption point in pre-trade

equilibrium for Thailand is shown by point E. The corresponding equilibrium

point for Japan is E* (panel (b) of Fig 2.5). The common slope of Thailand's

production possibilities curve (MN) and one of its social indifference curve 1 at E

is different from the corresponding common slope at E* (tangent lines have not

been drawn). In fact, the tangent line at E will be steeper than that at E*. This

means that the pre-trade equilibrium price of cloth is higher in Thailand than in

Japan. Alternatively we can say that before trade food is cheaper in Thailand than

in Japan. The law of comparative advantage would dictate that Japan exports

cloth and Thailand food. But we are yet to examine whether this trade pattern can

make both the countries better off than before trade.

Both Thailand and Japan will in fact, be better off if they can trade with each other

at a price ratio falling in a range whose limits are set by the (absolute) slopes of

the tangents at E and E*. Let us suppose that the slope at E is such that 1unit of

cloth exchanges for 6 units of food (i.e. the relative price of cloth P C

/P
F

is 6).

Therefore Thailand has to sacrifice 6 units of food for a unit of cloth. We make a

corresponding assumption about the pre-trade cloth price in Japan. Specifically we

assume that in pre-trade equilibrium one unit of cloth exchanges for 2 units of

food in Japan. In other words, in equilibrium Japan is willing (and able) to

sacrifice 2 units of food for a unit of cloth. If we denote the relative price of cloth

by P C

/P
F

, then on the basis of the above, we can write

P
C
P
F

Thailand

P
C
P
F

Japan

If trade begins, Thailand will export food and Japan cloth. As the trade flows

continue, the relative price of cloth in Thailand will tend to fall (the relative price

of food tends to rise). Resources in Thailand will, therefore, be withdrawn from

the production of cloth and used in the production of more food. This is a natural

response of profit maximizing producers to changing relative prices. The opposite

happens in Japan. Trade tends to increase the relative price of cloth (because it

exports cloth decreasing domestic cloth supply and imports food augmenting

domestic food availability). This makes cloth production more profitable at the

margin than before. Resources are reallocated such that some of the resources

engaged in food production are now used for increasing cloth production.

This tendency of the relative price of cloth to change under the impact of trade

flows will continue until the price is the same in both countries and trade is

balanced (the values of each country's exports and imports are equal). Let us

suppose that the equilibrium international price ratio is such that 1 unit of cloth

exchanges for 5 units of food (note that this is in between the pre-trade price

ratios). In Fig. 2.5, the common international price ratio is shown by the common

(absolute) slope of line KG (Thailand) and KG (Japan). The production point in

Thailand has shifted from E (before trade) to Q (after trade); it has increased the

production of food in which it has comparative advantage and decreased the

production of cloth in which it has comparative disadvantage. The opposite must

have happened in Japan. Its production point shifts from E* (before trade) to R*

(after trade), thus increasing the production of cloth in which it enjoys

comparative advantage.

The welfare

level is

indicated by

social

indifference

curve.

The principle of

comparative

advantage

remains valid as

an explanation

of the trade

patterns, even

under

increasing

opportunity

costs.

Fig. 2.

It is easy to see that both countries gain because trade opens up the possibility for

each country to trade at a price ratio different from that prevailing in each country

before trade. The total gain for each can be split into two components, namely, the

consumption gain (due to reallocation of consumption alone) and the production

gain (due to reallocation of production alone). Take the case of Thailand. Even if

there were no scope for reallocation of production after trade (i.e. if production

were kept frozen at E), it can gain by trading at the international price indicated by

line KG. To see how, imagine a line parallel to KG which passes through the point

E. The line will represent new consumption possibilities opened up for Thailand

even though production is fixed at E. It should be clear from the diagram that

Thailand can reach a higher level of social welfare than attained at E simply by

reallocation of consumption to a point on the new consumption frontier. This

represents the consumption gain. Production gain arises from the possibility of

production reallocation according to comparative (cost) advantage. If production

reallocation is possible and production shifts from E to Q, the consumption

opportunity line now becomes KG (which is further out from the line imaged

above). This represents a larger consumption opportunity set. The welfare level

attained now is indicated by social indifference curve 2 (point R). The increase in

welfare in this second step is the production gain. The total gain in welfare is

represented by the climb from social indifference curve 1 to 2. It is now easy to

see that the other country (Japan) also gains from trade by moving from a lower

social indifference curve 1* to a higher one (2*).

In summary, we can say that under the increasing cost situation also, the trade

pattern can be explained as in the simple Ricardian model in terms of comparative

advantage.

Haberler has aptly remarked, the principle of comparative advantage remains valid

as an explanation of the trade patterns in the same way as "a building remains

after the scaffolding, having served its purpose, is removed." The building

remains, but some of its old features are gone; trade no longer leads to complete

specialization and the price ratio is no longer dictated by technology alone.

According to

the Heckscher-

Ohlin theory,

countries

usually export

those goods that

use their

abundant

factors

intensively.

Answer: 1.C, 2.A, 3.A, 4.C, 5.D

Lesson 3 : The Heckscher Ohlin Model and Related

Theorems

Lesson Objectives:

After studying this lesson, you will be able to

 explain the Heckscher-Ohlin model;

 explain the Rybczynski theorem;

 appreciate the Stolper Samuelson theorem and

 understand the Factor Price Equalization theorem.

The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Neither David Ricardo nor other classical economists provided any clear-out

answer to the question : What is the ultimate determinant of comparative

advantage? Ricardo emphasized differences in technology, but there was no

explicit explanation of why such differences should arise, except implying

indirectly that they might be due to climatic differences between countries.

As we have seen before, even though two countries can differ (in the Ricardian

model) in respect of taste, technology and size of the productive labour force,

Ricardo found only the technological differences crucial for trade, the other two

being irrelevant, if the technologies did not differ. By adding more factors of

production, the Heckscher-Ohlin model brings to the fore a fourth kind of

difference, namely, that the proportions in which two countries are endowed with

various factors of production can vary. Two noted Swedish economists, Eli

Heckscher (1879-1952) and Berfil Ohlin (1899-1979) emphasized these

differences in factor proportions in their explanation of comparative advantage

and trade. Their ideas revolve around two key assumptions :

(i) Production of different goods require different factor proportions ; and

(ii) Countries vary in respect of their endowed factor abundance.

According to the Heckscher-Ohlin theory, countries usually export those goods

that use their abundant factors intensively. For this reason, the Heckscher-Ohlin

theory is also called the factor-proportions theory. Its plausibility is almost

immediate when we see that labour abundant countries like Korea and Taiwan

export footwear, textiles and sugar (labour-intensive goods), while the land

abundant countries like Australia, Canada and Argentina export meat, wheat, and

wool (land-intensive products).

Assumptions of the Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) Model

Like all models (because they need abstractions), the H-O model too is based on

several simplifying assumptions, not all of which are required for the validity of all

the propositions of the general H-O model. These are:

  1. 2x2x2 assumption: There are two countries (America and Britain) each

having two homogeneous factors of production (capital and labour) and

producing two goods (cloth and steel). This is why the model is also referred

to as the 2x2x2 model.

Trade can lead

to the equality

of relative

commodity

prices between

nations.

Perfect

competition will

drive the

producer of

each good to

select only one

input ratio (one

technique) for

any given level

of output.

  1. Technology and the nature of production function: The two goods are

produced with identical production technologies in each country. Moreover,

the production functions exhibit constant returns to scale. This implies that a

proportionate increase in all inputs will lead to the same proportionate

increase in all output. The production function in the two countries being

identical, this will ensure that the producer of a commodity in the two

countries will use exactly the same quantities of labour and capital for a unit

of the commodity, if they face the same factor price ratio.

  1. Strong factor intensity: One commodity (cloth) is always labour-intensive

compared to the other (say, steel). This means that whatever the wage-rental

ratio, cloth uses more labour per unit of capital than steel. This assumption is

needed to rule out any possibility of factor-intensity reversal, which is

particularly damaging to H-O conclusions. Factor intensity reversal occurs

when, for example, cloth is labour-intensive at lower wage-rental ratios, but

become capital-intensive at high wage rental ratios.

  1. Perfect Competition: All commodity and factor prices are determined in

perfectly competitive markets.

  1. Factor mobility : For the law of one price to prevail, it is assumed that all

factors are absolutely free to move between industries of the same country.

By contrast factors are assumed to be completely immobile between

countries.

  1. Tastes : Tastes are required to be largely similar, but they need not be

identical.

  1. Free trade : Trade between nations is free from all artificial interferences like

tariffs, quotas and exchange control.

  1. Transportation costs : These are assumed to be zero. Because of this

assumption, trade can lead to the equality of relative commodity prices

between nations.

Meaning of Factor Intensity and Factor abundance

Assume that two goods, cloth and steel, are produced in each country by one

technique alone. For instance, a unit of cloth requires 8 units of labour and 2 units

of capital, while a unit of steel requires 2 units of labour and 8 units of capital.

These input requirement data are presented in Table 2.6.

Table 2.

Commodity Input per unit of output Capital Labour

(K/L)

Cloth Capital (K) Labour (L)

2÷8=

Steel 8 2 8 ÷ 2=

Clearly the capital-labour ratio in the production of cloth is lower than in the

production of steel (

<4). Since there is only one process by which each good

can be produced, we can unambiguously say that steel is more capital-intensive

than cloth. Or equivalently, cloth is more labour-intensive than steel.

A difficulty may apparently arise if cloth and steel can be produced using many

possible techniques (e.g., along a smooth isoquant). But even here we can apply